Friday 9 December 2016

On the loss of American Manufacturing jobs.

Just as the semester is wrapping up we have had the chance to cover the final two chapters in Micro and Macro.

In Micro we had the chance to briefly look at environmental economics -- which has been making some prominent headlines in the news with the discussion of a federal carbon emission tax ... but we will save these headlines for a follow-up post.

First, I bring attention to an interesting article I came across in "The Atlantic" by Jared Bernstein and Dean Baker titled "Why Trade Deficits Matter".

For those of you in my Macro class - to relate this to what we discussed, this article falls right along the line of the familiar, traditional, almost mercantilist argument of "Exports are good, imports are bad", that is the false underlying belief that trade is a zero-sum game.

The argument which Bernstein and Banker make is that the view held by us economists that current account deficits are harmless and no different in effect than current account surpluses are, in fact, wrong.

The argument which they are referring too ... as far as I could decipher at least, follows the basic premise:


  1. Following trade liberalisation, industry in each country will align itself along the sectors with a comparative advantage (lowest opportunity cost of production). 
  2. Thus industries in the export sector will expand, while industries in the importing sector will contract -- however given a basic premise of scarce resources, in order for the export sector to expand, it needs to utilise the released resources from the contracting import sector. 
Thus my interpretation of the argument being made is that because we have a prolonged trade deficit, (Imports are greater than exports) then this must mean that more jobs have been lost in the import sector (manufacturing) than have been gained in the export sector. 

Thus it is due to a prolonged trade deficit that we have weak demand (aggregate demand) resulting in a persistent recessionary output gap and high rates of overall unemployment. Thus to fix the problem Bernstein and Banker argues that we need to restore the trade balance and reduce the current account deficit. 

while it may be the case that there has been a correlation between the trade deficit and higher rates of unemployment in the states, I was extremely sceptical of the argument being made by Bernstein and Banker. I had a feeling that this was a case of correlation, not causation. (Remember just because A and B are correlated does not mean that A causes B or that B causes A, In fact, there could be a C that causes both!)

Specifically, I would have expected trade to have the effects mentioned above - regardless of trade surplus or deficit. 

As the US economy reallocates its resources to support its export industry (contracting the import industry) - jobs are created in the export industry, while jobs are lost in the import industry. The problem is, many of the skills or education held by the recently laid off labour (and capital) in the import industry may not be relevant for employment in the exporting industry. 

Although the exporting industry wants to hire more workers, the present labour force does not have the skills or education which is demanded by the export sector. As a result, we have a rising level of structural unemployment. I felt this would especially be the case given the exceptionally high cost faced by workers in the US to retrain due to the high cost of schooling.

This was at least my thoughts on the matter, however, these were based on some grand assumptions as I lacked (and lack) the actual data and information about the US economy, as well as other economies who may be experiencing the same thing, but with a current account surplus. 

Then by luck, I came across this article on Forbes by Tim Worstall "Memo for Trump...". Worstall does not comment on the rise of structural unemployment the same ways I hypothesised above, rather Worstall argues that manufacturing jobs are on the decline globally, and this holds for countries both with trade surpluses and deficits. 

Worstall makes the argument, which seems well founded from my view, that through the rise of new manufacturing technologies, productivity has risen, and as a result, there has been less demand for manufacturing jobs. Thus, the manufacturing worker has found themselves hard pressed for employment regardless of if they find themselves in a country where manufacturing is the export/import sector, or if they find themselves in a country with a trade surplus/deficit. 

With this bit of insight (and data) in mind, it would seem that the US manufacturing sector has two serious headwinds to face. 

  1. The manufacturing industry in the US does not have a comparative advantage in relation to foreign countries, and thus finds itself in the position of the import sector - struggling to remain competitive. As a result, firms struggle to maintain a profit, and exit the industry, releasing their capital and labour for the export sector to utilise. however, realistically, we will first see a period of higher structural unemployment as the labour retrains and the capital is 're-purposed'.
  2. Globally, manufacturing is shifting to capital intensive methods of production. this rise of technology, further displaces manufacturing workers, further adding to the structural unemployment. 
With these two headwinds in mind ... what can be done to save American manufacturing jobs? we could ignore the changing economy and put up protectionist measures in order to save these manufacturing jobs ... but this just delays the inevitable. (and , could potentially slow the shifting of scarce resources to the trying to expand export industry, thus limiting national income). 

Or alternatively, we could rethink the institutional makeup, and craft some forward thinking policies aimed at reducing the structural unemployment caused by these pressures. Specifically, subsidised education reduces the enormous cost of retraining, allowing laid off workers (who are already facing a cost of lost wages and uncertainty of future job prospects) to retrain, and reenter the job market at a much more rapid rate than we are potentially seeing. 

However this last point I make without any hard evidence, other than looking at other countries (Canada, Germany) which also have witnessed pains in their manufacturing sectors, but through subsidised education, have greatly reduced the cost of retraining, allowing these workers to upgrade their skills rather than be relegated to low-paying, low-skill jobs, which is what I am continually being told is happening to these manufacturing workers by the US media.

There is of course much more to this discussion! please feel free to continue the conversation in the comments below.





No comments:

Post a Comment

The high cost of low taxes - Fiscal Policy part 2

                 In this post, we will spend some time talking about the high costs of low taxes. This may seem somewhat paradoxical; we wil...